America's Saving Rate: Thoughts on Savings (Part 1 of 2)

Mike Shedlock examines what savings are, what they’re not, and explains why America’s negative Saving Rate is a serious problem.

SOMEONE RECENTLY TOLD me he was saving by contributing to his 401(k).
Another person told me he was saving by paying off his home mortgage quicker.
Both of those may be wise decisions, but are they savings?
In the strictest definition, savings are that part of your production that is in excess of your consumption. Money is merely a means of channeling, or storing, your saved production. Once you’ve exchanged your real savings for money and go on to invest, you have replaced your savings with investment, while transferring the claim to your savings to someone else.

Under that definition, it is clear that paying down one’s house mortgage, paying off credit card debts, or investing in the stock market is simply not saving. That does not imply these are bad ideas, it just means they are not savings.

Frank Shostak discusses this concept in “Have We Saved Enough?” Let’s take a look:

“If a baker produces 10 loaves of bread and consumes one loaf, his saving is nine loaves of bread. In other words, saving is the baker’s real income (his production of bread) minus the amount of bread that the baker consumed. The baker’s saving now permits him to secure other goods and services.
“For instance, the baker can now exchange his saved bread for a pair of shoes with a shoemaker. Observe that the baker’s saving is his real means of payment — he pays for the shoes with the saved bread. Likewise, the shoemaker pays for the nine loaves of bread with the shoes that are his real saving.

“The introduction of money doesn’t alter what we have so far said. When a baker sells his bread for money to a shoemaker, he has supplied the shoemaker with his saved unconsumed bread. The supplied bread sustains the shoemaker and allows him to continue making shoes. Note that the money received by the baker is fully backed up by his unconsumed production of bread…

“Money enables the goods of one specialist to be exchanged for the goods of another specialist. In short, by means of money, people can channel real savings, which in turn permits the widening of the process of real wealth generation…

“Now what about the case where money is used to buy unprocessed material — is the unprocessed material real saving? The answer is no. The raw material must be processed and then converted into a piece of equipment, which in turn can be employed in the production of final goods and services that are ready for human consumption. In this sense, the buyer of unprocessed material transfers his claims on real savings to the seller of material in return for the prospect that the transformed material some time in the future will generate benefits far in excess of the cost incurred.”

If I quoted everything of merit in that article, I would be reproducing it in its entirety. The concept is important, so I suggest it is a worthwhile read. Before continuing on, let’s quickly point out that expansion of money supply, whether or not that money ends up in savings accounts, is not savings, either. That concept can easily be proven by adding an extra zero to everyone’s paycheck, and, of course, to the cost of goods as well. Savings have not increased; only the denomination of money has. When it comes to home prices, what good does it do you if your home has doubled in price when a replacement home will have doubled in price as well? Of course, this does not even delve into the very real possibility that asset prices just might drop.

America’s Saving Rate: Deferring Current Consumption
Stephen Roach discussed savings on Sept. 9 in an article entitled, “The Shoestring Economy.” This is one of his better articles as of late, and following are the highlights:

“Never in modern history has the world’s leading economic power tried to do so much with so little. A saving-short U.S. economy has long pushed the envelope in drawing on foreign capital to subsidize excess consumption. But now Washington is upping the ante as it opens the fiscal spigot to cope with post-Katrina reconstruction at the same time it is funding the ongoing war in Iraq. Could this be a tipping point for America’s shoestring economy?”
For any economy, saving is emblematic of the willingness to defer current consumption in order to invest in the future. America’s problem is that it no longer saves. Its net national saving rate — the combined saving of individuals, businesses, and the government sector (all adjusted for depreciation) — has fallen to a record low of only 1.5% of GNP since early 2002. By contrast, this same national saving rate averaged 7.5% over the 40-year period 1960-2000. Unwilling to cut back on investment, a saving-short U.S. economy has become increasingly dependent on surplus foreign saving in order to grow.

Asset-dependent consumers were running a negative personal saving rate to the tune of negative 0.6% of disposable personal income in July 2005. Not since the Great Depression of the early 1930s have U.S. households been stretched that far. Yet today, few seem worried about this development. Conventional wisdom has it that “rational” consumers have uncovered new and permanent sources of saving in the form of rapid asset appreciation — first equities and now homes…. The American consumer is on the leading edge of the shoestring economy.

The government sector is in a similar position. So far, the Bush administration has hit Congress with $62 billion in supplemental spending requests in the immediate aftermath of Katrina. The risk is that these disaster-relief appropriations are only a down payment on the final tab, which eventually will span the gamut — from infrastructure repair and reconstruction of housing and commercial areas to massive environmental cleanup efforts. In the politically charged post-Katrina environment, any semblance of fiscal discipline has vanished into thin air. Next year’s federal budget deficit is currently projected at minus 2.4% of GDP; a conservative estimate of a post-Katrina budget could easily push that figure into the minus 3.25-3.5% range — virtually identical to peak cyclical shortfalls hit in 2003-04.

One of two things has to happen — either the United States attempts to maintain its current lifestyle and places a greater claim on surplus saving elsewhere in the world, or there is a consolidation of discretionary spending by American households and businesses, alike.

The macro conclusions are inescapable: A saving-short U.S. economy that runs a massive current account deficit is effectively living beyond its means. It not only relies on foreign saving to fund domestic growth, but it also lacks the capacity to invest in public goods that may be needed to safeguard its future. Lacking in domestic saving, the shoestring economy is also biased toward chronic underinvestment in infrastructure — leaving itself vulnerable to “breakage.” Whether that breakage comes from within (i.e., Katrina) or from outside (i.e., terrorism), the shoestring economy runs the risk of being unprepared to ward off such blows in a fragile and dangerous world. An energy shock exacerbates the imbalances that produce such vulnerability. This draws into serious question the resilience that financial markets now seem to be banking on.

According to the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, for the month of July, personal income increased $29.3 billion, or 0.3%, and disposable personal income (DPI) increased $27.2 billion, or 0.3%. Personal consumption expenditures (PCE) increased $85.7 billion, or 1%. In June, personal income increased $54.7 billion, or 0.5%; DPI increased $45.9 billion, or 0.5%; and PCE increased $88.0 billion, or 1%, based on revised estimates.
In plain English, disposable income went up $27.2 billion (0.3%), but spending went up $88 billion (1%).

America’s Saving Rate: Chart Highlights

Here are the interesting highlights:

1) Private wage and salary disbursements increased $29.4 billion in July, compared with an increase of $17.9 billion in June

2) Personal outlays — PCE, personal interest payments, and personal current transfer payments — increased $86.8 billion in July, compared with an increase of $92.8 billion in June. PCE increased $85.7 billion, compared with an increase of $88 billion

3) Proprietors’ income decreased $3.5 billion in July, in contrast with an increase of $14.7 billion in June

4) Farm proprietors’ income decreased $0.5 billion, compared with a decrease of $0.8 billion

5) Nonfarm proprietors’ income decreased $3 billion, in contrast with an increase of $15.5 billion

6) Rental income of persons decreased $3.3 billion in July, compared with a decrease of $4.3 billion in June Personal income receipts on assets (personal interest income plus personal dividend income) increased $7.8 billion, compared with an increase of $18 billion.

7) Personal current transfer receipts decreased $4.2 billion, in contrast with an increase of $5.6 billion

8) Contributions for government social insurance — a subtraction in calculating personal income — increased $3.6 billion in July, compared with an increase of $2.1 billion in June.

This is the bottom line:
Personal saving, disposable personal income less personal outlays, was $-58.8 billion in July, in contrast with $0.9 billion in June. Personal saving as a percentage of disposable personal income was a negative 0.6% in July, compared with 0% in June.

Negative personal saving reflects personal outlays that exceed disposable personal income. Saving from current income may be near zero or negative when outlays are financed by borrowing (including borrowing financed through credit cards or home equity loans), by selling investments or other assets, or by using savings from previous periods. Not only are we not saving, we are now borrowing simply to support consumption.

On that note, Mish is taking telepathic questions. Hmmm, questions just came pouring in. Let’s address them while the telepathic lines are still open.
Q1) Mish, has the United States always been a nation of spending fools?

A1) No, as hard as it might be for some to remember, as recently as 1992, the savings rate in the United States was as high as 10%. Here is a chart to prove it:
phpirFraf

Q2) Mish, what does retail spending look like now as compared with historical growth?

A2) It seems as if we are now treating our houses as ATMs, since wage growth is not keeping up. I offer this chart as evidence:

phpdPpEhO

Q3) Mish, is there any evidence of consumer stress as a result of all this spending?

A3) Yes, indeed, there is. We are finally starting to see a big uptick in mortgage defaults and delinquencies. As long as home prices allowed equity extraction, everyone was OK. Unfortunately, it now seems that appreciation has not kept up with expenditures. I offer the following chart as proof:

phpJlDAxj

Note that PMI defaults bottomed in April but have ticked up every month since then. Also note that cures (those that were in delinquent but managed to catch up), topped in February and have been declining ever since. This is a clear sign that rising home prices are no longer sustaining consumption, at least in some areas. Watch what happens when housing prices take a serious hit in California or Florida. It will not be pretty.
Mike Shedlock / Mish
September 13, 2005

The Daily Reckoning